Friedrich Bernard Christian Maassen

 Jean Mabillon

 Mabinogion

 Diocese of Macao

 St. Macarius

 Macarius Magnes

 Macarius of Antioch

 Edward McCabe

 Hugh MacCaghwell

 Denis Florence MacCarthy

 Nicholas Tuite MacCarthy

 John McCloskey

 William George McCloskey

 John MacDonald

 Alexander Macdonell

 Mace

 Francisco Macedo

 José Agostinho de Macedo

 United Sees of Macerata and Tolentino

 Francis Patrick McFarland

 Thomas D'Arcy McGee

 James MacGeoghegan

 Machabees

 Books of Machabees

 John MacHale

 Nicolò Machiavelli

 Machpelah

 St. Machutus

 Vicariate Apostolic of Mackenzie

 John McLoughlin

 Marie-Edmé-Patrice-Maurice de MacMahon

 Martin Thomas McMahon

 James Alphonsus McMaster

 William James MacNeven

 Ancient Diocese of Mâcon

 Bernard John McQuaid

 Macri

 Macrina

 James McSherry (1)

 James McSherry (2)

 Richard McSherry

 Mactaris

 Madagascar

 Madaurus, or Madaura

 Carlo Maderna

 Stefano Maderno

 Madianites

 Archdiocese of Madras

 Diocese of Madrid-Alcalá

 Christopher Madruzzi

 Madura Mission

 St. Maedoc

 St. Maelruan

 St. Maelrubha

 Jacob van Maerlant

 Maestro di Camera del Papa

 Bernardino Maffei

 Francesco Maffei

 Raffaelo Maffei

 Antoine-Dominique Magaud

 Magdala

 Magdalens

 Magdeburg

 Mageddo

 Ferdinand Magellan

 Magi

 Magin Catalá

 Simone de Magistris

 Antonio Magliabechi

 Magna Carta

 Magnesia

 Alphonse Magnien

 Magnificat

 St. Magnus

 Olaus Magnus

 Valerianus Magnus

 John Macrory Magrath

 Magydus

 Ven. Charles Mahony

 Angelo Mai

 Emmanuel Maignan

 Joseph-Anna-Marie de Moyria de Mailla

 Antoine-Simon Maillard

 Olivier Maillard

 Louis Maimbourg

 Teaching of Moses Maimonides

 Maina Indians

 Maine

 François-Pierre-Gonthier Maine de Biran

 Françoise, Marquise de Maintenon

 Mainz

 Maipure Indians

 Joseph-Marie, Comte de Maistre

 Xavier de Maistre

 Diocese of Maitland

 Benedetto da Majano

 Diocese of Majorca and Iviza

 Majordomo

 Majority

 Paul Majunke

 Malabar

 Malabar Rites

 Diocese of Malacca

 Malachias

 St. Malachy

 Diocese of Malaga

 Gabriel Malagrida

 House of Malatesta

 Malchus

 Juan Maldonado

 Nicolas Malebranche

 Malediction (in Scripture)

 François Malherbe

 Maliseet Indians

 Ernest-François Mallard

 Hermann von Mallinckrodt

 Pauline Mallinckrodt

 Stephen Russell Mallory

 Mallus

 Malmesbury

 Monk of Malmesbury

 William Malone

 Sir Thomas Malory

 Marcello Malpighi

 Malta

 Claude Maltret

 Thomas Malvenda

 Malvern

 Thomas Maria Mamachi

 Alfred-Henri-Amand Mame

 Mameluco

 Mamertine Prison

 St. Mamertus

 Mammon

 Man

 Manahem

 St. Manahen

 Manasses

 Jeanne Mance

 Diocese of Manchester

 Manchuria

 Mandan Indians

 Jean de Mandeville

 Archdiocese of Manfredonia

 Diocese of Mangalore

 James Clarence Mangan

 Manharter

 Manichæism

 Manifestation of Conscience

 Archdiocese of Manila

 Manila Observatory

 Maniple

 Manitoba

 Theodore Augustine Mann

 Manna

 Henry Edward Manning

 Robert Mannyng of Brunne

 Mansard

 Gian Domenico Mansi

 Andrea Mantegna

 Mantelletta

 Diocese of Mantua

 Laws of Manu

 Manuel Chysoloras

 Manuscripts

 Illuminated Manuscripts

 Manuscripts of the Bible

 Manuterge

 Aldus Manutius

 Alessandro Manzoni

 Walter Map

 Maphrian

 Prudentius Maran

 Marash

 Carlo Maratta

 Marbodius

 Pierre de Marca

 St. Marcellina

 Pope St. Marcellinus

 Flavius Marcellinus

 Marcellinus Comes

 Marcellinus of Civezza, O.F.M.

 Benedetto Marcello

 Pope St. Marcellus I

 Pope Marcellus II

 Marcellus of Ancyra

 Auzias March

 Jean Baptiste Marchand

 Peter Marchant

 Pompeo Marchesi

 Giuseppe Marchi

 Marcian

 Marciane

 Marcianopolis

 Marcionites

 Marcopolis

 Marcosians

 Joseph Marcoux

 Marcus

 Marcus Diadochus

 Marcus Eremita

 Mardin

 Ambrose Maréchal

 Marenco

 Luca Marenzio

 St. Margaret

 Bl. Margaret Colonna

 Margaret Haughery

 St. Margaret Mary Alacoque

 St. Margaret of Cortona

 Bl. Margaret of Hungary

 Bl. Margaret of Lorraine

 Bl. Margaret of Savoy

 St. Margaret of Scotland

 Margaret of the Blessed Sacrament

 Bl. Margaret Pole

 Margaritae

 Antonio Margil

 Giacomo Margotti

 Maria-Laach

 Xantes Mariales

 Juan Mariana

 Archdiocese of Mariana

 Prefecture Apostolic of Mariana Islands

 Congregation of the Missionaries of Mariannhill

 Marian Priests

 Marianus of Florence

 Marianus Scotus

 Maria Theresa

 Marie Antoinette

 Bl. Marie Christine of Savoy

 Marie de France

 Bl. Marie de l'Incarnation

 Ven. Marie de l'Incarnation

 Marienberg

 Marini

 Luigi Gaetano Marini

 Pope Marinus I

 Pope Marinus II

 Edme Mariotte

 Sts. Maris, Martha, Audifax, and Abachum

 Adam de Marisco

 St. Marius Aventicus

 Lucius Perpetuus Aurelianus Marius Maximus

 Marius Mercator

 St. Mark

 Pope St. Mark

 Gospel of Saint Mark

 Sts. Mark and Marcellian

 Mark of Lisbon

 Paul Maroni

 Maronia

 Maronites

 Vicariate Apostolic of Marquesas Islands

 Diocese of Marquette

 Jacques Marquette

 Marquette League

 Civil Marriage

 History of Marriage

 Mixed Marriage

 Moral and Canonical Aspect of Marriage

 Mystical Marriage

 Ritual of Marriage

 Sacrament of Marriage

 Florence Marryat

 Diocese of Marseilles (Massilia)

 Thomas William Marshall

 Vicariate Apostolic of the Marshall Islands

 Diocese of Marsi

 Diocese of Marsico Nuovo and Potenza

 Luigi Ferdinando, Count de Marsigli

 Marsilius of Padua

 Edmond Martène

 St. Martha

 St. Martial

 John Martiall

 Jean Martianay

 Martianus Capella

 Joseph-Alexandre Martigny

 Pope St. Martin I

 Pope Martin IV

 Pope Martin V

 Martin

 Felix Martin

 Gregory Martin

 Konrad Martin

 Paulin Martin

 St. Martina

 Antonio Martini

 Martino Martini

 Simone Martini

 Diocese of Martinique

 St. Martin of Braga

 St. Martin of Leon

 St. Martin of Tours

 Martin of Troppau

 Martin of Valencia

 John Martinov

 Martinsberg

 George Martinuzzi

 Luis Martin y Garcia

 Martyr

 Peter Martyr d'Anghiera

 Martyrology

 Martyropolis

 Acts of the Martyrs

 Japanese Martyrs

 The Ten Thousand Martyrs

 Martyrs in China

 St. Maruthas

 Mary of Cleophas

 Little Brothers of Mary

 Missionaries of the Company of Mary

 Servants of Mary (Order of Servites)

 Society of Mary (Marist Fathers)

 Society of Mary of Paris

 Name of Mary (1)

 Bl. Mary Anne de Paredes

 Mary de Cervellione

 Ven. Mary de Sales Chappuis

 St. Mary Frances of the Five Wounds of Jesus

 Maryland

 St. Mary Magdalen

 St. Mary Magdalen de' Pazzi

 St. Mary of Egypt

 Mary Queen of Scots

 Mary Tudor

 Masaccio

 Mascoutens Indians

 Masolino da Panicale

 Richard Angelus a S. Francisco Mason

 Masonry (Freemasonry)

 Maspha

 Chapter and Conventual Mass

 Liturgy of the Mass

 Volume 11

 Music of the Mass

 Nuptial Mass

 Sacrifice of the Mass

 Massa Candida

 Diocese of Massa Carrara

 Massachusetts

 Guglielmo Massaia

 Diocese of Massa Marittima

 Enemond Massé

 Bequests for Masses (Canada)

 Bequests for Masses (England)

 Devises and Bequests for Masses (United States)

 Jean-Baptiste Massillon

 Massorah

 Antoine Massoulié

 René Massuet

 Quentin Massys

 Master of the Sacred Palace

 Bartholomew Mastrius

 Mataco Indians

 Mater

 Materialism

 Feast of the Maternity of the Blessed Virgin Mary

 Mathathias

 Theobald Mathew

 François-Désiré Mathieu

 Mathusala

 St. Matilda

 Matilda of Canossa

 Matins

 Matricula

 Matteo da Siena

 Matteo of Aquasparta

 Matter

 Carlo Matteucci

 St. Matthew

 Gospel of St. Matthew

 Sir Tobie Matthew

 Matthew of Cracow

 St. Matthias

 Matthias Corvinus

 Matthias of Neuburg

 Maundy Thursday

 Auguste-François Maunoury

 St. Maurice

 Maurice

 Maurists

 St. Maurus

 Sylvester Maurus

 Jean-Siffrein Maury

 Joannes Maxentius

 Marcus Aurelius Maxentius

 Ven. Thomas Maxfield

 Maximianopolis

 Marcus Aurelius Valerius Maximianus

 Maximilian

 Maximilian I

 St. Maximinus

 Caius Valerius Daja Maximinus

 Caius Julius Verus Maximinus Thrax

 Maximopolis

 St. Maximus of Constantinople

 St. Maximus of Turin

 William Maxwell

 Winifred Maxwell

 Maya Indians

 Christian Mayer

 Edward Mayhew

 Bl. Cuthbert Mayne

 Maynooth College

 School of Mayo

 Mayo Indians

 John Mayor

 Mayoruna Indians

 Prefecture Apostolic of Mayotte, Nossi-Bé, and Comoro

 Beda Mayr

 Francis Mayron

 Jules Mazarin

 Mazatec Indians

 Charles Joseph Eugene de Mazenod

 Diocese of Mazzara del Vallo

 Camillo Mazzella

 Lodovico Mazzolini

 Sylvester Mazzolini

 Pietro Francesco Mazzuchelli

 Mbaya Indians

 Thomas Francis Meagher

 Diocese of Meath

 Diocese of Meaux

 Mecca

 Mechanism

 Mechitar

 Mechitarists

 Archdiocese of Mechlin

 Johann Mechtel

 St. Mechtilde

 Mechtild of Magdeburg

 Mecklenburg

 Jean Paul Medaille

 Devotional Medals

 St. Medardus

 Medea

 Archdiocese of Medellín

 Media and Medes

 Mediator (Christ as Mediator)

 Hieronymus Medices

 House of Medici

 Maria de' Medici

 History of Medicine

 Medicine and Canon Law

 Bartholomew Medina

 Juan de Medina

 Miguel de Medina

 Francisco Medrano

 Andreas Medulic

 Charles Patrick Meehan

 Megara

 Megarians

 Antoine-Joseph Mège

 Mehrerau

 Guillaume-René Meignan

 Jean-Baptiste Meilleur

 Bl. Meinwerk

 Meissen

 Ernest Meissonier

 Philipp Melanchthon

 St. Melania (the Younger)

 Archdiocese of Melbourne

 Paul Melchers

 Melchisedech

 Melchisedechians

 Melchites

 Juan Meléndez Valdés

 Meletius of Antioch

 Meletius of Lycopolis

 Diocese of Melfi and Rapolla

 Giovanni Meli

 Pius Melia

 Melissus of Samos

 Melitene

 St. Melito

 Abbey and Congregation of Melk

 Melleray

 Abbey of Mellifont

 St. Mellitus

 Diocese of Melo

 Melos

 Melozzo da Forlí

 Abbey of Melrose

 Chronicle of Melrose

 Francesco Melzi

 Memberton

 Zenobius Membre

 Hans Memling

 Memory

 Memphis

 Juan de Mena

 Menaion

 Léon Ménard

 Nicolas-Hugues Ménard

 René Ménard

 St. Menas

 Mencius

 Alvaro de Mendaña de Neyra

 Diocese of Mende

 Mendel, Mendelism

 João Mendes de Silva

 Vicariate Apostolic of Méndez and Gualaquiza

 Manuel de Mendiburu

 Mendicant Friars

 Jerónimo Mendieta

 Diego Hurtade de Mendoza

 Francisco Sarmiento de Mendoza

 Pedro Gonzalez de Mendoza

 Osorio Francisco Meneses

 Diocese of Menevia

 Gregorio Mengarini

 Anthon Rafael Mengs

 Mennas

 Mennonites

 Giovanni Stefano Menochio

 Men of Understanding

 Menologium

 Menominee Indians

 Mensa, Mensal Revenue

 John Mensing

 Mental Reservation

 Johannes Mentelin

 Benedetto Menzini

 Eustache Mercadé

 Mercedarians

 Louis-Honoré Mercier

 Geronimo Mercuriali

 Brothers of Our Lady of Mercy

 Corporal and Spiritual Works of Mercy

 Sisters of Mercy

 Sisters of Mercy of St. Borromeo

 Edward Meredith

 Diocese of Mérida

 Merit

 Gaspard Mermillod

 Merneptah I

 Frédéric-François-Xavier Ghislain de Mérode

 Marin Mersenne

 Mesa

 Delegation Apostolic of Mesopotamia, Kurdistan, and Armenia

 Mesrob

 Messalians

 Messene

 Messias

 Antonello da Messina

 Archdiocese of Messina

 Thomas Messingham

 Metal-Work in the Service of the Church

 Symeon Metaphrastes

 Metaphysics

 Pietro Metastasio

 Edward Metcalfe

 Metellopolis

 Metempsychosis

 Sir Thomas Metham

 Methodism

 St. Methodius of Olympus

 Methymna

 Metrophanes of Smyrna

 Metropolis

 Metropolitan

 Prince Klemens Lothar Wenzel von Metternich

 Metz

 Jean Clopinel de Meun

 Mexico

 Archdiocese of Mexico

 Francis, Joseph, and Paul Mezger

 Giuseppe Mezzofanti

 Miami Indians

 Military Orders of St. Michael

 Michael Cærularius

 St. Michael de Sanctis

 Michael of Cesena

 Michael Scotus

 St. Michael the Archangel

 Joseph-François Michaud

 Micheas (Micah)

 Jean Michel

 Michelians

 Edward Michelis

 Michelozzo di Bartolommeo

 Michigan

 Archdiocese of Michoacan

 Adam Mickiewicz

 Micmacs

 Micrologus

 Jakob Middendorp

 Middle Ages

 Diocese of Middlesbrough

 Midrashim

 Midwives

 Christoph Anton Migazzi

 Pierre Mignard

 Jacques-Paul Migne

 Migration

 Archdiocese of Milan

 Vinzenz Eduard Milde

 George Henry Miles

 Diocese of Mileto

 Miletopolis

 Miletus

 Vitus Miletus

 Milevum

 Jan Milic

 Military Orders

 Millennium and Millenarianism

 Ferdinand von Miller

 Jean-François Millet

 Pierre Millet

 John Milner

 Ven. Ralph Milner

 Milo Crispin

 Milopotamos

 Pope St. Miltiades

 Karl von Miltiz

 Diocese of Milwaukee

 Mind

 Diocese of Minden

 John Ming

 Minimi

 Minister

 Jean-Pierre Minkelers

 Minnesota

 Minor

 Diocese of Minorca

 Minor Orders

 Diocese of Minsk

 Papal Mint

 Minucius Felix

 Mirabilia Urbis Romæ

 Miracle

 Miracle Plays and Mysteries

 Gift of Miracles

 Aubert Miraeus

 Giovanni Francesco Pico della Mirandola

 Giovanni Pico della Mirandola

 Abbey of Miridite

 Miserere

 Congregation of the Sisters of Misericorde

 Prefecture Apostolic of Misocco and Calanca

 Missal

 Congregation of Priests of the Mission

 Congregation of Missionaries of St. Charles Borromeo

 Missionaries of St. Francis de Sales of Annecy

 Missionary Society of St. Paul the Apostle

 Mission Indians (of California)

 Catholic Missions

 Catholic Indian Missions of Canada

 Catholic Indian Missions of the United States

 Catholic Parochial Missions

 Mississippi

 Missouri

 Mithraism

 Mitre

 Nicola Giacomo Mittarelli

 Mitylene

 St. George Jackson Mivart

 Mixe Indians

 Mixteca Indians

 Moab, Moabites

 Diocese of Mobile

 Mocissus

 Mocoví Indians

 Archdiocese of Modena

 Modernism

 Diocese of Modigliana

 Modra

 Mohammedan Confraternities

 Mohammed and Mohammedanism

 Archdiocese of Mohileff

 Johann Adam Möhler

 Christian Mohr

 Joseph Mohr

 François-Napoléon-Marie Moigno

 Jacques de Molai

 Notre-Dame de Molesme

 Diocese of Molfetta, Terlizzi, and Giovinazzo

 Jean-Baptiste Poquelin Molière

 Alonso de Molina

 Antonio de Molina

 Juan Ignacio Molina

 Luis de Molina

 Molinism

 Miguel de Molinos

 Wilhelm Molitor

 Francis Molloy

 Gerald Molloy

 Gasparo Molo

 Moloch

 Molokai

 Sir Caryll Molyneux

 Bonino Mombritius

 Principality and Diocese of Monaco

 Monad

 Monarchians

 Monarchia Sicula

 Double Monasteries

 Suppression of Monasteries

 Canonical Erection of a Monastery

 Monasticism

 Francisco de Moncada

 Mondino dei Lucci

 Diocese of Mondoñedo

 Diocese of Mondovi

 Franz Mone

 Moneta

 Mongolia

 St. Monica

 Monism

 Monita Secreta

 Monk

 Monogram of Christ

 Monomotapa

 Monophysites and Monophysitism

 Diocese of Monopoli

 Moral Aspects of Monopoly

 Monotheism

 Monothelitism and Monothelites

 Archdiocese of Monreale

 James Monroe

 Jacques-Marie-Louis Monsabré

 Monseigneur

 William Monsell, Baron Emly

 Monsignor

 Enguerrand de Monstrelet

 Bartolomeo Montagna

 Montagnais Indians (Quebec)

 Montagnais Indians (Chippewayans)

 Michel-Eyquen de Montaigne

 Diocese of Montalcino

 Charles-Forbes-René, Comte de Montalembert

 Diocese of Montalto

 Montana

 Juan Martínez Montañés

 Montanists

 Diocese of Montauban

 Xavier Barbier de Montault

 Bl. Peter of Montboissier

 Marquis de Louis-Joseph Montcalm-Gozon

 Abbey of Monte Cassino

 Diocese of Montefeltro

 Diocese of Montefiascone

 Jorge de Montemayor

 Montenegro

 Diocese of Montepulciano

 Diocese of Monterey and Los Angeles

 Military Order of Montesa

 Antonio Montesino

 Luis de Montesinos

 Montes Pietatis

 Charles-Louis de Secondat, Baron de Montesquieu

 Claudio Monteverde

 Monte Vergine

 Archdiocese of Montevideo

 Bernard de Montfaucon

 Simon de Montfort

 Joseph-Michel Montgolfier

 Special Devotions for Months

 Charles Huault de Montmagny

 John de Montmirail

 Anne, First Duke of Montmorency

 Alexis-François Artaud de Montor

 Diocese of Montpellier

 Archdiocese of Montreal

 Montreuil

 Montreuil Abbey

 Mont-St-Michel

 Antoine-Jean-Baptiste-Robert Auget, Baron de Montyon

 Arthur Moore

 Michael Moore

 Thomas Moore

 Mopsuestia

 Antonis Van Dashorst Mor

 Ambrosio Morales

 Juan Bautista Morales

 Luis de Morales

 Moralities

 Morality

 Leandro Fernandez de Moratín

 Moravia

 Stefano Antonio Morcelli

 Helen More

 Henry More

 Gall Morel

 Juliana Morell

 José María Morelos

 Louis Moréri

 Augustín Moreto y Cabaña

 Giovanni Battista Morgagni

 Ven. Edward Morgan

 Raffaello Morghen

 David Moriarty

 Michelangelo Morigi

 Abbey of Morimond

 Jean Morin

 Mormons

 Morocco

 Giovanni Morone

 Gaetano Moroni

 Giovanni Battista Moroni

 John Morris

 John Brande Morris

 Martin Ferdinand Morris

 Morse

 Ven. Henry Morse

 Mortification

 Mortmain

 John Morton

 Ven. Robert Morton

 Mosaic Legislation

 Mosaics

 Johannes Moschus

 Moscow

 Moses

 Moses Bar Cephas

 Moses of Chorene

 Mossul

 Dioceses of Mostar and Markana-Trebinje

 Feast of the Most Pure Heart of Mary

 Mosynoupolis

 Motet

 Toribio de Benavente Motolinia

 Motu Proprio

 Antoine de Mouchy

 Franz Christoph Ignaz Moufang

 Diocese of Moulins

 Congregations of Mount Calvary

 Feast of Our Lady of Mount Carmel

 Mount St. Mary's College

 Franz Karl Movers

 Moxos Indians

 Karl Ernst, Freiherr von Moy de Sons

 Ven. John Martin Moye

 Francis Moylan

 Stephen Moylan

 Mozambique

 Mozarabic Rite

 Johann Chrysostomus Wolfgang Amadeus Mozart

 Mozetena Indians

 Mozzetta

 Luigi Mozzi

 Ignatius Mrak

 Albert Anton Von Muchar

 Engelbert Mühlbacher

 Michael George Mulhall

 St. Clair Augustine Mulholland

 John Mullanphy

 Adam Heinrich Müller

 Johann Müller

 Johann Müller (Regiomontanus)

 Karl Müller

 John T. Mullock

 Baron Eligius Franz Joseph von Münch-Bellinghausen

 Fintan Mundwiler

 Archdiocese of Munich-Freising

 Diocese of Munkács

 Diocese of Münster

 University of Münster

 Eugène Müntz

 St. Mura

 Luigi Antonio Muratori

 Muratorian Canon

 Marc-Antoine Muret

 Muri

 Bartolomé Esteban Murillo

 Thomas Murner

 Diocese of Muro-Lucano

 Daniel Murray

 Patrick Murray

 Christian Museums

 Mush

 John Mush

 Ecclesiastical Music

 Musical Instruments in Church Services

 Musti

 Markos Musuros

 José Celestino Mutis

 Alfonso Muzzarelli

 Mylasa

 Myndus

 Myra

 Myrina

 Myriophytum

 Diocese of Mysore

 Mystery

 Mystical Body of the Church

 Mysticism

Moral Aspects of Monopoly


According to its etymology, monopoly (monopolia) signifies exclusive sale, or exclusive privilege of selling. Present usage, however, extends the term to any degree of unified control over a commodity sufficient to enable the person or corporation in control to limit supply and fix price. The proportion of the supply of an article that must be controlled in order to attain these ends, depends upon many factors, and differs considerably in different industries. In the majority of monopolized businesses, it is somewhere between 70 and 90 per cent, although there are cases in which the unified control of a little more than one half the supply of the commodity seems to suffice. In most of the cases in which the monopoly controls less than three-fourths of a business, the independent dealers seem to have the power to overthrow the monopoly but prefer to take advantage of the higher prices and steadier market conditions established by the dominant concern. They are, consequently, passive factors in the monopolized condition of the trade. No matter how great the degree of control which the monopoly enjoys, its power over supply and prices is not absolute. Many economic and prudential considerations will restrain a monopoly from exercising this power to the extent that it might desire — for example, the fear of potential competition, the discovery of a substitute for the monopolized article, or the possibility that people may get on without either the article or a substitute. But in all cases monopoly implies the ability deliberately to regulate supply and prices beforehand, and to fix both at some other point than that which would have been reached by the natural action of the market under normal competition. However inexpedient a monopoly may be, it is not in itself immoral. Its moral character depends entirely upon its actions and its effects. More specifically, its morality is determined by the prices that it establishes, and the methods that it employs toward actual or potential competitors.


I. MONOPOLISTIC PRICES

According to the older moral theologians, monopoly prices were unjust when they were higher than the prices that would have prevailed under competition (cf. Lugo, "De Justitia et de Jure", disp. xxvi, n. 72). While this rule was substantially correct for the Middle Ages, when the competitive, or rather the customary, price was generally fair to both producers and consumers, it is far from acceptable to-day, when the competitive price is often too low to provide a just return to the agents of production. For competitive prices, as well as for monopoly prices, the objective rule of justice is that a thing should be sold at a price sufficiently high to remunerate fairly all who have contributed to the production of the thing; the subjective rule of justice is the social estimate, the price approved by competent and fair-minded men (cf. Tanquerey, "De Justitia", 776). If the monopoly price does not exceed these limits, it is not unjustly high, even though it be higher than the price that had obtained or would have obtained under the stress of competition. Since the different classes that help to produce a socially useful commodity have a right to a fair return for their services, and since this return can come only from the price at which the commodity is sold, the latter is unjustly low unless it is sufficient for this purpose. There is no hidden force in competition by which an unjust price can be made just. On the other hand, there is no secret virtue in monopoly to justify a selling price that is more than sufficient to render fair returns to the different agents of production. These propositions are accepted by the overwhelming majority of persons, whether experts or not: the practical, and the only serious difficulty is to determine precisely what is a fair return to each of the different agents.

Putting the matter as briefly and as summarily as possible, we may say that a just remuneration to the agents of production comprises: (1) a living wage for all labourers, and something more than this for those workers who possess exceptional ability or skill, who put forth unusual efforts, who perform disagreeable tasks, or who turn out exceptionally large products; (2) fair profits for the business man, on account of his activities as director of industry; (3) a fair rate of interest on the actual capital invested in the business. Fair recompense for the captain of industry in a monopoly will generally mean the amount that he could obtain in return for the same services in a competitive business. Although competition is not of itself a determinant of fair wages in the case of ordinary labour, inasmuch as it often forces remuneration below the level of decent living, it is generally fair to the director of industry, inasmuch as it enables him not merely to obtain a decent livelihood, but to maintain himself in accordance with that higher standard of living to which he has a reasonable claim. And it yields even more than this to those business men whose ability is exceptional. A fair rate of interest on monopoly capital will be the rate that prevails in competitive businesses that are subject to a like amount of risk. The capitalist or interest receiver as such, does not work, but is free to earn his livelihood by his labour from other sources. Thus, since interest is not his sole means of livelihood, the just rate of interest is not determined by, nor does it bear any definite relation to, the content of a decent livelihood in the individual case. Consequently, competition may be the proper rule of justice for the interest receiver, as well as for the director of industry, although it is not always a just rule for the ordinary wage-earner.

What are the grounds for the assertion that the investor in a monopoly has no right to more than the competitive or prevailing rate of interest? The answer to this question is bound up with the more fundamental question concerning the basis of the right of any investor to receive any interest at all. But, no matter what answer we give to this latter question, no matter what justification of interest we may adopt, we cannot prove, we can have no ground upon which to erect the beginnings of a proof, that the capitalist has a right, as capitalist, to more than the prevailing or competitive rate of interest. If we assume that interest is justified as the product or fruit of capital, we have no reason to assert that the so-called product has a higher value than men attribute to it in the open market under competitive conditions. If we regard interest as the due reward of the capitalist's sacrifices in saving, we have no ground for maintaining that these are not fully remunerated in the current rate. If we adopt the theory that seems to be most satisfactory and least assailable, namely that interest is chiefly justified on grounds of social utility, inasmuch as the community would probably not have sufficient capital unless men were encouraged to save by the hope of interest, we must likewise conclude that the current competitive rate is sufficiently high, since it brings forth sufficient saving and sufficient capital for society's needs. The argument based upon this theory may be stated summarily as follows: Since interest on capital cannot be shown to be unjust on individual grounds, that is as a payment from the purchaser of the product of capital to the owner of capital (for it must be remembered that the consumer is the real and final provider of interest on capital), it will be justified on social grounds if it is necessary in order to evoke sufficient social capital; and there is an overwhelming probability that it is necessary for this purpose. Since interest is justified only for this purpose and to this extent, the just rate of interest cannot be higher than the rate that attains this end, which in our time is the competitive rate.

The doctrine that capital has no right to more than the competitive rate of interest is accepted by the social estimate everywhere (see Final Report of the U.S. Industrial Commission, p. 409). It is implicitly asserted in the teaching of the theologians that the competitive rate is the just rate in the case of money loaned (cf. Tanquerey, "De Justitia", n. 906). Where the risk and other circumstances are the same, men do not value an investment any higher than a loan; they will put their money into the one or the other indifferently; consequently, it would seem clear that, when the circumstances just referred to are the same, a fair return on invested money need not exceed a fair return on loaned money. To be sure, investors and business men do obtain more than the competitive rate of interest in some years and in some enterprises, even where competition is active and constant; but this advantage is either offset by exceptionally low rates in other years, or it is due to unusual business ability, or it arises from an increase in the value of the land connected with the enterprise. In all these cases the exceptionally high rate is undoubtedly lawful morally, but the excess is due to other factors than the capital pure and simple. Since the prevailing or competitive rate is sufficiently high to satisfy the demands of justice in businesses that are subject to competition, there seems to be no good reason why it is not, generally speaking, sufficiently high in monopolistic concerns. The owner of a monopoly has no more right to take advantage of the helplessness of the consumer in order to extort an exceptionally high rate of interest on his investment than the money-lender has to exploit the distress of the borrower in order to exact an exorbitant rate of interest on the loan. It would seem that the only exception to this rule would occur when the monopoly, while paying a fair wage to labour and a fair price to those from whom it buys materials, introduces economies of production which enable it to sell its goods at less than the prices charged by its competitors, and yet make unusual profits and interest on its investment. In such a case it seems reasonable that a monopolistic concern (more properly, its active directors, who alone have effected the productive economies) should receive some of the benefits of the cheaper methods of production. On the other hand, there is no good reason why the monopoly should appropriate all the benefits of the improvement. If it does not share them with the consumer by reducing prices below the competitive level, it renders no social service to compensate for the social danger which is inherent in every monopolistic enterprise. As a matter of fact, the great majority of existing monopolies do not pay higher wages nor higher prices for material than competitive concerns, and yet they charge the consumer higher prices than would have prevailed under competition (cf. Final Report of the Industrial Commission, pp. 621, 625, 660).

In the preceding paragraphs reference is had to monopolistic concerns that fix prices without any supervision or restriction by the State. When the public authority exercises adequate control over the charges of public service monopolies, such as gas and street-railway companies, and determines these freely and honestly, it would seem that the monopolistic corporation has a right to collect the full amount of the charges established by the public authorities, even though they should yield unusual profits on the investment, for the presumption is that such charges are fair to both producer and consumer. No such presumption extends to those cases in which the state control over charges is only mildly corrective and partial, instead of fundamental and thorough.


II. MONOPOLISTIC METHODS

The methods and practices employed by monopolies in dealing with their rivals did not occupy the attention of the older moral theologians who wrote on the subject of monopoly. Nor have recent writers given this phase of the subject the attention that it deserves. As a consequence, authoritative ethical teaching is as yet silent, whereas public opinion regards as immoral most of the practices by which monopolistic concerns harass and eliminate their competitors. Among the most notable of these methods are discriminative underselling, the factor's agreement, and railway favouritism.

Discriminative underselling occurs when the monopoly sells its goods at unprofitably low prices in the territory in which it wishes to destroy competition, while imposing unreasonably high prices elsewhere. While the independent dealer who is driven out of business by this device has no strict right to the patronage of the customers who are drawn away from him through the low prices established by the monopoly, he has a right not to be deprived of that patronage by unjust methods. According to a general and far-reaching moral principle, a man is unjustly treated when he is prevented by unjust means from obtaining an advantage which he has a right to pursue (cf. Lehmkuhl, "Theologia Moralis", I, n. 974; Tanquerey, "De Justitia", n. 588). Among the unjust means enumerated by the moral theologians are: force, fraud, deception, falsehood, intimidation, and extortion. Now when a manufacturer or a merchant is deprived of the patronage of his customers through ruinously low prices, which the monopoly is enabled to maintain by means of the exorbitantly high prices that it establishes at another place or time, he is deprived of this advantage by unjust means. The unjustly high prices are as truly the means by which the independent dealer is injured, as the lying reports brought to a would-be benefactor are the means by which his intended beneficiary is deprived of a legacy. This is the stock example used by the moral theologians to illustrate the general principle stated above. When, however, a business concern eliminates a competitor by lowering prices universally, and keeping them low even after the latter has gone out of business, no injustice is done, because no unjust means are employed. Even when a monopolistic concern lowers prices everywhere at the same time, and raises them to an unjust level only after its competitors have been driven from the field, the latter would seem to be victims of injustice. For, although the unjust prices do not come into existence until after the injury has been accomplished, they are as certainly the means whereby the injury was done, as though they had been established simultaneously with the ruinously low prices. In both cases the exorbitant prices operate as the moral cause of the act by which the unprofitably low prices are established.

The factor's agreement is exemplified when a merchant engages to handle no goods, or no goods of a certain kind, except those manufactured by a monopoly; should the merchant decline to enter into this agreement, the monopolistic concern will refuse to sell him any goods at all. If the agreement is established, the result is that the rivals of the monopolistic manufacturing concern are deprived of the patronage of the merchant through intimidation. It is a species of secondary boycott, inasmuch as the monopoly refuses to have business intercourse with the merchant, unless the latter refuses to do business with the independent manufacturer. It seems sufficiently clear that boycotts of this kind are unreasonable and unjust whenever, as in this instance, there exists no sufficient reason for the intimidation and the refusal of intercourse (see LABOUR UNIONS, MORAL ASPECTS OF). Indeed, the motive of the monopoly is, as a rule, not merely lacking in reasonableness, but positively unjust; for its ultimate aim is not simply to acquire the patronage that now goes to its rivals, but in addition to raise prices to the consumer after its rivals have been eliminated.

Railway favouritism is the most important of all the methods of monopoly. It has in all probability been as effective in creating and maintaining monopolies as all the other methods combined. It appears under many forms, but its essence is found in the fact that the goods dealt in by a monopoly are carried by the railroad at a rate so much below that charged to independent dealers that the latter must either go out of business or be content with insufficient profits. This practice is undoubtedly immoral: (1) because it is forbidden by the civil law; (2) because the railroad, as a quasi-public agency, is under obligation to treat all its patrons with the same distributive justice that the state itself would be obliged to accord them if it were the owner of the railroads; (3) because the lower charges collected from the monopoly imply unjustly high charges extorted from the independent shippers. As a violation of the civil law, railway favouritism is against legal justice; as unequal treatment of different patrons, it is a violation of both distributive and commutative justice, precisely as the unequal imposition of taxes violates both these forms of justice. If the rate accorded to the monopoly for carrying its goods is sufficiently high to be just, the higher rate imposed upon its rivals exceeds the limits of justice. If the former rate is so low as to be unremunerative to the railroad, the injustice done to the independent dealers is still greater, inasmuch as they are compelled to bear a part of the charges that should be defrayed by the monopoly. The favours accorded to the latter are not deducted from the normal revenues and profits of the railway company.

As a matter of purely natural justice, a railroad might concede somewhat lower carrying rates to a monopolistic concern because the monopoly ships goods in larger lots. The cost of such transportation is always smaller than when the same volume of goods is carried in separate lots for several different concerns. Nevertheless, even this degree of favouritism is a violation of legal justice, and frequently a violation of charity as regards the smaller shipping concerns. Inasmuch as the practice of railway favouritism to monopolies is seldom confined within these narrow limits, the question raised in this paragraph is not of much practical importance. Again, the railroad might be absolved from the charge of violating natural justice if the lower rates which it extended to the monopoly did not fall below the lowest level (pretium infimum) of justice, while the charges exacted from the independent shippers did not exceed the highest level (pretium summum) sanctioned by justice. A private enterprise, such as a mercantile concern, could probably be absolved from the stigma of injustice if it indulged in this practice toward its different customers. But, as we have seen above, a railway is not a purely private concern. Since it performs a quasi-public function, it would seem to be bound by the same rules of distributive justice that would govern the State, if the latter were operating the business of transportation. The share of the monopoly in the immorality and injustice connected with railway favouritism consists in the fact that it requests, urges, and sometimes intimidates the railway to indulge in the practice. The monopoly is therefore a co-operator. In the language of the moral theologians, it is a mandans, or principaI, and likewise a participans, or beneficiary (frequently the only beneficiary) of the injustice done to its rivals through overcharges for transportation.

While monopoly is not necessarily unjust, and while any particular monopoly may be free from unjust practices, experience shows that the power to commit injustice which is included in monopoly cannot be unreservedly entrusted to the average human being or group of human beings. Consequently, it is the duty of public authority to prevent the existence of unnecessary monopolies, and to exercise such supervision over necessary monopolies as to render impossible monopolistic injustice, whether against the independent business man through unjust methods, or the consumer through unjust prices. Many of the moral judgments enunciated in this article will perhaps strike the reader as lacking in positiveness, inasmuch as they are modified by such phrases as "it would seem," "it is probable," "it is reasonable". Yet no other course was possible. Concerning most of the specific questions discussed in the foregoing pages, there exists no specific teaching by the Church, or even by the unanimous voice of theologians. There are not even well-defined bodies of theological opinion. All that can be done is to draw conclusions from, and make specific applications of, the more general principles of justice as found in approved Catholic sources.

ELY, Monopolies and Trusts (New York, 1900); RIPLEY, Trusts, Pools, and Corporations (New York, 1905); Reports of U. S. Industrial Commission, I; IX (Washington, 1903); HOWE, Privilege and Democracy in America (New York, 1910); BLISS, New Encyclopedia of Social Reform, s. v. Trusts; SLATER in Irish Theological Quarterly (July, 1906); RYAN, ibid. (July, 1908); LUGO, De Justitia et de Jure (Lyons, 1670); TANQUEREY, De Justitia, (New York, 1904); LEHMKUHL, Theologia Moralis, I (Freiburg, 1893); VERMEERSCH, Quaestiones de Justitia (Bruges, 1901); . JANNET, Le Capital, la Speculation et la Finance (Paris, 1892).

John A. Ryan.